File Download

There are no files associated with this item.

  Links for fulltext
     (May Require Subscription)
Supplementary

Article: Trust and Reciprocity in Firms’ Capacity Sharing

TitleTrust and Reciprocity in Firms’ Capacity Sharing
Authors
Issue Date1-Mar-2023
PublisherInstitute for Operations Research and Management Sciences
Citation
Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 2023 How to Cite?
AbstractProblem definition: We study the use of nonmonetary incentives based on reciprocity to facilitate capacity sharing between two service providers that have limited and substitutable service capacity. Academic/practical relevance: We propose a parsimonious game theory framework, in which two firms dynamically choose whether to accept each other’s customers without the capability to perfectly monitor each other’s capacity utilization state. Methodology: We solve the continuous-time imperfect-monitoring game by focusing on a class of public strategy, in which firms’ real-time capacity-sharing decision depends on an intuitive and easy-to-implement accounting device, namely the current net number of transferred customers. We refer to such an equilibrium as a trading-favors equilibrium. We characterize the condition in which capacity sharing takes place in such an equilibrium. Results: We find that some degree of efficiency loss (as compared with a central planner’s solution) is necessary to induce reciprocity. The efficiency loss is small when the two firms have similar traffic intensity even if they are different in service-capacity scale, whereas the efficiency loss can be considerably large when the two firms have significantly different traffic intensities. The trading-favors mechanism, surprisingly, can outperform the perfect-monitoring benchmark when the two firms exhibit high asymmetry in terms of service-capacity scale or traffic intensity because the smaller firm tends to deviate from collaboration. Managerial implications: Firms should consider engaging in nonmonetary reciprocal capacity sharing if regulations, transaction costs, or other market and operational frictions make it difficult to use a capacity-sharing contract based on monetary payments. The trading-favors collaboration can improve the firms’ payoff close to the centralized upper bound when the firms have similar traffic intensities. However, when their traffic intensities are highly different, firms are better off with a monetary-payment contract to induce more capacity sharing and are worse off investing in increasing their visibility to each other’s real-time available capacity, namely investing in perfect monitoring.
Persistent Identifierhttp://hdl.handle.net/10722/328373
ISSN
2023 Impact Factor: 4.8
2023 SCImago Journal Rankings: 5.466
ISI Accession Number ID

 

DC FieldValueLanguage
dc.contributor.authorHu, Xing-
dc.contributor.authorCaldentey, René-
dc.date.accessioned2023-06-28T04:43:37Z-
dc.date.available2023-06-28T04:43:37Z-
dc.date.issued2023-03-01-
dc.identifier.citationManufacturing & Service Operations Management, 2023-
dc.identifier.issn1523-4614-
dc.identifier.urihttp://hdl.handle.net/10722/328373-
dc.description.abstractProblem definition: We study the use of nonmonetary incentives based on reciprocity to facilitate capacity sharing between two service providers that have limited and substitutable service capacity. Academic/practical relevance: We propose a parsimonious game theory framework, in which two firms dynamically choose whether to accept each other’s customers without the capability to perfectly monitor each other’s capacity utilization state. Methodology: We solve the continuous-time imperfect-monitoring game by focusing on a class of public strategy, in which firms’ real-time capacity-sharing decision depends on an intuitive and easy-to-implement accounting device, namely the current net number of transferred customers. We refer to such an equilibrium as a trading-favors equilibrium. We characterize the condition in which capacity sharing takes place in such an equilibrium. Results: We find that some degree of efficiency loss (as compared with a central planner’s solution) is necessary to induce reciprocity. The efficiency loss is small when the two firms have similar traffic intensity even if they are different in service-capacity scale, whereas the efficiency loss can be considerably large when the two firms have significantly different traffic intensities. The trading-favors mechanism, surprisingly, can outperform the perfect-monitoring benchmark when the two firms exhibit high asymmetry in terms of service-capacity scale or traffic intensity because the smaller firm tends to deviate from collaboration. Managerial implications: Firms should consider engaging in nonmonetary reciprocal capacity sharing if regulations, transaction costs, or other market and operational frictions make it difficult to use a capacity-sharing contract based on monetary payments. The trading-favors collaboration can improve the firms’ payoff close to the centralized upper bound when the firms have similar traffic intensities. However, when their traffic intensities are highly different, firms are better off with a monetary-payment contract to induce more capacity sharing and are worse off investing in increasing their visibility to each other’s real-time available capacity, namely investing in perfect monitoring.-
dc.languageeng-
dc.publisherInstitute for Operations Research and Management Sciences-
dc.relation.ispartofManufacturing & Service Operations Management-
dc.titleTrust and Reciprocity in Firms’ Capacity Sharing-
dc.typeArticle-
dc.identifier.doi10.1287/msom.2023.1203-
dc.identifier.hkuros344662-
dc.identifier.eissn1526-5498-
dc.identifier.isiWOS:000954577400001-
dc.identifier.issnl1523-4614-

Export via OAI-PMH Interface in XML Formats


OR


Export to Other Non-XML Formats