File Download

There are no files associated with this item.

  Links for fulltext
     (May Require Subscription)
Supplementary

Book Chapter: Imagining China: Brazil, labor, and the limits of an anti-model

TitleImagining China: Brazil, labor, and the limits of an anti-model
Authors
Issue Date2017
Citation
The Beijing Consensus?: How China has Changed Western Ideas of Law and Economic Development, 2017, p. 43-68 How to Cite?
Abstract© Cambridge University Press 2017. The idea of a consensus in development discourse is ever alluring. Much like discussions of universal '‘best practices,'' asserting the existence of a consensus offers up the possibility that the most fundamental, if oft-elided, challenge of development has been transcended - that of politics. Especially in the postcolonial era, the universal language of empirical social science has, at its best, expanded the possibility of cross-cultural knowledge exchange while, at its worst, fallen prey to merely cloaking cultural chauvinism or geopolitical self-interest. In this way, the rise of the Washington Consensus was itself as much the construction of a particular vein of development economics as it was an outgrowth of the 1990s post-Soviet euphoria that gave rise to the claim that the United States had achieved a demonstrable and well-understood economic track record. A track record that could be universalized into a model that was powerful enough to transcend global socio-cultural diversity, much akin to Francis Fukuyama’s proclaimed end of history. In similar stead, the relative decline of the influence of the Washington Consensus reflects as much concerns about the empirical validation of its underlying policy prescriptions as it does the end of the 1990s optimistic imagining of a unipolar liberal world order. Understanding the rise of the idea of the Beijing Consensus thus begs the question of what would generate interest in a new '‘consensus’' in a very different, multipolar, geopolitical context. Such search for an alternative was presaged by the focus in the 1980s on Japan as the source of a new '‘alternative’' model of development, spurred then by the Japanese economic and international discord following stagflation and energy crises in the West during the late 1970s. This chapter will argue that the contemporary geopolitical context and backlash against the Washington Consensus has given rise to the use and invocation of the Beijing Consensus as an anti-model. As an anti-model, the Beijing Consensus discourse is only partly a reaction against the underlying policy content of the Washington Consensus. More fully, it is also a general rejection of the very notion of the coordinated global advocacy of a universal set of policy prescriptions. This observation is not in itself completely novel.
Persistent Identifierhttp://hdl.handle.net/10722/260195

 

DC FieldValueLanguage
dc.contributor.authorKroncke, Jedidiah-
dc.date.accessioned2018-09-12T02:00:42Z-
dc.date.available2018-09-12T02:00:42Z-
dc.date.issued2017-
dc.identifier.citationThe Beijing Consensus?: How China has Changed Western Ideas of Law and Economic Development, 2017, p. 43-68-
dc.identifier.urihttp://hdl.handle.net/10722/260195-
dc.description.abstract© Cambridge University Press 2017. The idea of a consensus in development discourse is ever alluring. Much like discussions of universal '‘best practices,'' asserting the existence of a consensus offers up the possibility that the most fundamental, if oft-elided, challenge of development has been transcended - that of politics. Especially in the postcolonial era, the universal language of empirical social science has, at its best, expanded the possibility of cross-cultural knowledge exchange while, at its worst, fallen prey to merely cloaking cultural chauvinism or geopolitical self-interest. In this way, the rise of the Washington Consensus was itself as much the construction of a particular vein of development economics as it was an outgrowth of the 1990s post-Soviet euphoria that gave rise to the claim that the United States had achieved a demonstrable and well-understood economic track record. A track record that could be universalized into a model that was powerful enough to transcend global socio-cultural diversity, much akin to Francis Fukuyama’s proclaimed end of history. In similar stead, the relative decline of the influence of the Washington Consensus reflects as much concerns about the empirical validation of its underlying policy prescriptions as it does the end of the 1990s optimistic imagining of a unipolar liberal world order. Understanding the rise of the idea of the Beijing Consensus thus begs the question of what would generate interest in a new '‘consensus’' in a very different, multipolar, geopolitical context. Such search for an alternative was presaged by the focus in the 1980s on Japan as the source of a new '‘alternative’' model of development, spurred then by the Japanese economic and international discord following stagflation and energy crises in the West during the late 1970s. This chapter will argue that the contemporary geopolitical context and backlash against the Washington Consensus has given rise to the use and invocation of the Beijing Consensus as an anti-model. As an anti-model, the Beijing Consensus discourse is only partly a reaction against the underlying policy content of the Washington Consensus. More fully, it is also a general rejection of the very notion of the coordinated global advocacy of a universal set of policy prescriptions. This observation is not in itself completely novel.-
dc.languageeng-
dc.relation.ispartofThe Beijing Consensus?: How China has Changed Western Ideas of Law and Economic Development-
dc.titleImagining China: Brazil, labor, and the limits of an anti-model-
dc.typeBook_Chapter-
dc.description.naturelink_to_subscribed_fulltext-
dc.identifier.doi10.1017/9781316481370.003-
dc.identifier.scopuseid_2-s2.0-85047917111-
dc.identifier.spage43-
dc.identifier.epage68-

Export via OAI-PMH Interface in XML Formats


OR


Export to Other Non-XML Formats